CDZ Free Trade vs. Protectionism

320 Years of History

Gold Member
Nov 1, 2015
6,060
822
255
Washington, D.C.
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
 
For folks who prefer a PowerPoint style discussion of the pros and cons of free trade and the politics associated with them, see the attached document.
 

Attachments

  • Free Trade Pros and Cons PowerPoint.pdf
    939.2 KB · Views: 212
Uncle Ferd says...

... "If we could just find a middle ground...

... dem Chinamens wouldn't be eatin' our lunch."
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
The USA is the #1 victim of imperialism in the world today, with $133 Billion/year being lost to remittances$$. That is American businesses losing all those sales to domestic outsourcing (AKA immigration & work visas) Tens of Billions more are lost by welfare to foreigners in the US. Protectionism puts a stop to this international burglary.

Then we have international outsourcing. Sure, it makes money for the few globalists who invest overseas, but they are not >> "economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it." That tag goes to ALL 318 million people in the country, and they need to be protected from international outsourcers, who cause American workers to lose jobs, and American businesses to thereby lose sales.
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism.
What is good for the majority is not always good for the individual. Many people with few skills are terrified of change since they may need more education to change careers or may have to relocate. Both are justifiably scary to many and they can't see past their short-time pain to the long-term gains that they may never benefit from.
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
The USA is the #1 victim of imperialism in the world today, with $133 Billion/year being lost to remittances$$. That is American businesses losing all those sales to domestic outsourcing (AKA immigration & work visas) Tens of Billions more are lost by welfare to foreigners in the US. Protectionism puts a stop to this international burglary.

Then we have international outsourcing. Sure, it makes money for the few globalists who invest overseas, but they are not >> "economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it." That tag goes to ALL 318 million people in the country, and they need to be protected from international outsourcers, who cause American workers to lose jobs, and American businesses to thereby lose sales.

So who's goods are you going to Tax...

And believe me this is a tax which will make goods in US go up. The Right is looking for a massive tax increase on a all the American people...

But who are you going to tax... Just
China and India or
All the world

How do you think the rest of the world is going to respond?
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
The USA is the #1 victim of imperialism in the world today,.

Wow, that's a whopper of a lie. Ours is a consumer-based economy and we can thank cheap labor throughout the world for getting cheap goods. So that makes us by far the biggest beneficiary to imperialism.
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
The USA is the #1 victim of imperialism in the world today,.

Wow, that's a whopper of a lie. Ours is a consumer-based economy and we can thank cheap labor throughout the world for getting cheap goods. So that makes us by far the biggest beneficiary to imperialism.

LOL My gut says I know what you mean because I've read many of your posts. My brain says that perhaps you should have chosen a phrasing other than "cheap goods." The other part of my brain is willing to go with my gut because of the contextually clarifying last sentence. LOL
 
Great post. I will have to read it all later.

I would add though, if I am placing a tariff on an imported car, the harm to the foreign producer is of zero concern to me.

There is also the side benefit of keeping a manufacturing industry in your country which just might be able to build aircraft, tanks and weapons in time of war. Think of Kia / Hyundai's learning curve with making automobiles. With military equipment you want it to be good from the get go.
 
Great post. I will have to read it all later.

I would add though, if I am placing a tariff on an imported car, the harm to the foreign producer is of zero concern to me.

There is also the side benefit of keeping a manufacturing industry in your country which just might be able to build aircraft, tanks and weapons in time of war. Think of Kia / Hyundai's learning curve with making automobiles. With military equipment you want it to be good from the get go.

Blue:
From a personal economic standpoint, I can understand your taking that stance. I suspect you won't care unless/until the tariff results in the foreign producer/nation retaliating in some say that does personally affect you. I'm not going to go into all the ways that can happen, but I will note that trade wars can have pretty far reaching impacts, especially upon nations which have many mature markets rather than having many "reaching maturity" markets. What nations tend to have more mature markets? Rich ones. That sort of thing didn't matter too much 50+ years ago, but with the world being "smaller" now, it matters a lot.

NAFTA is a great treaty to examine and it has been examined quite a lot:

Red:
Right...that, for U.S. citizens, is essentially an emotional benefit, and, yes, it's good to feel good about something. Practically speaking, however, the U.S. maintains a domestic aerospace/defense manufacturing capability and that's not going to stop being so. That is what Boeing, Northrop-Grumman, BAE and others build, among other things. There certainly are components we purchase abroad and there are raw materials that we buy from other nations. Whether we "have to" or "just choose to" is unknown to me, as is the nature of the "musts vs opt to" choices we make.

I'm aware of and have read some articles about the matter, but I have yet to read a more recent unclassified document that discusses the matter in detail and that clearly identifies the risks and unforced vs. forced manufacturing constraints the U.S. faces in this regard. I think the best one might come across is this one, which was produced by students at the Eisenhower School; however, it doesn't include content from some of the nation's most important defense contractors. Another somewhat decent document that addresses the topic is this one: Annual Industrial Capabilities Report to Congress.

Some of the other content I've perused includes:
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
Trade policies, when leveraged against your own workers, makes a nation weaker and investor class wealthier. China is taking advantage of weak U.S. leacership. But because you most likely never worked a blue collar job in your life you belive in the "magic" of free trade.
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
Trade policies, when leveraged against your own workers, makes a nation weaker and investor class wealthier. China is taking advantage of weak U.S. leacership. But because you most likely never worked a blue collar job in your life you belive in the "magic" of free trade.

Well, I can't do anything about why and how you manage to feel as though you can legitimately assert/postulate why I accept that free trade's benefits outweigh it's downsides, most especially given the content one'll find at the links I provided in the OP.
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
Trade policies, when leveraged against your own workers, makes a nation weaker and investor class wealthier. China is taking advantage of weak U.S. leacership. But because you most likely never worked a blue collar job in your life you belive in the "magic" of free trade.

Well, I can't do anything about why and how you manage to feel as though you can legitimately assert/postulate why I accept that free trade's benefits outweigh it's downsides, most especially given the content one'll find at the links I provided in the OP.
How has so called "free trade" helped the United Stead? How does it help when Wal Mart is your top civilian employer? Would we have been a global super power in 1962 if Woolworh was are top employer? Department stores and dollar stores does not make you a strong country.
 
I don't know what drives the fascination and seeming preference for economic protectionism. There quite simply is no greater economic/financial well being to an economy and the people in it from tariffs, subsidies and quotas than there is by not having them. That is well understood by every single economist on the planet. It is Econ 101 for high school students and it is plain to see in very simple graphs.

unit-4-international-economics_9.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

What to notice about the impact of a tariff: Domestic producers benefit at the expense of domestic consumers and foreign producers. The green triangles represent efficiency or well being lost because that isconsumer surplus that is forgone after the tariff. The yellow rectangle is not deadweight loss because it is tariff revenue for the government.

Be sure to note the indirect effects of tariffs. For example, any of the three forms of protection shown in this post -- tariffs, quotas and subsidies -- will lead to a decrease in net exports for America’s trading partners, which means a decrease in Aggregate Demand and the possibility of higher unemployment, recession, lowerincome, thus less demand for American products abroad. So, not only does the tariff hurt American consumers through higher prices and lower quantity, but it harms other American businesses whose products are no longer in demand from foreigners whose incomes have declined thanks to the American tariffs.

Note also the regressive nature of tariffs. Much like a VAT or an excise tax, tariffs place a greater burden on low income earners than high income earners, as a particular tax on imports represents a larger percentage of a poor person’s income.

unit-4-international-economics_11.png


(DWL = deadweight loss)

Subsidies appear to result in less of a financial well being loss to society than tariffs, but this is unclear since the size of the subsidy is unknown. Obviously, larger subsidies create a greater welfare loss, because they result in more scarce resources being allocated towards the production of a product which the US lacks acomparative advantage. The size of the green triangle in the graph above represents the size of the welfare loss… or the degree to which resources are being over-allocated towards this product.

The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

unit-4-international-economics_12.png


The Quota scenario is the most complicated to understand graphically. Here’s how to interpret the graph above. The government says that foreigners can only import Q1 to Q2 units, which means at Pw, where American firms are only producing 0 to Q1 units, there is a severe shortage of automobiles. The price rises in response to the excess demand, which attracts more firms into the automobile market (or existing firms open new plants) shifting domestic Supply out.

The price will settle where the new domestic Supply curve intersects demand, but the number of cars produced by American firms will equal 0Q4 minus Q1Q2. In other words, since foreigners were happy to import Q1 to Q3 even at the lower Pw before the quota, they will continue to import as much as they are allowed (equal to the government’s quota of Q1Q2 at the new higher price. But since consumers demand Q4 at the new higher price, new domestic producers will step in and satisfy the demand beyond what foreign firms can meet with their restricted imports. So the domestic output is represented by two segments, 0Q1 and Q2Q4. Imports are represented by Q1Q2 (restricted by the government’s quota). Confusing, but once you study it for a while it makes sense.


The charts and discussion above is the easy way to understand tariffs, quotas and subsidies. If you'd prefer to understand the above concepts by working through the math that makes it so, check out the content at the links below. To come to the same understanding, you'll need to do a lot more work -- it's the same work high school and college econ students perform when learning about how tariffs, quotas and subsidies work -- to arrive at the conclusions noted above.
  • Tariffs examined in real world situations -- The first problem (water with and without VAT, which is the tariff in that example) is all you will need to solve. You'll need to create your own graphs, but what you'll end up with, assuming you do the math correctly and accurately graph your work, is graphs like the ones above.
  • Why politicians like protectionist policies -- After studying how tariffs, quotas and subsidies (protectionist policies), you will be able to see how the cost of having them is "hidden." Of course, it's only hidden to folks who don't know how they work. Once one knows how they work, they're not hidden at all, but it does take some doing (as the exercise above will illustrate if you perform it) to quantify the so-called "hidden" costs of the protections.
  • Simplifying difficult calculations: consumer choice of two-part tariffs -- This document explains how businesses can implement their own tariff system to drive consumer choice. Though the focus of the discussion in this document is not about governmental policy, it illustrates how the very same "hidden" nature of a tariff can be used by businesses to drive many/most consumers to choose a product that yields higher revenue/profit for the business. If you're familiar with the various schemes that cell phone service providers/carriers offer as go service and equipment, you've seen this idea in action.
  • Tariffs and Quotas: Effects on Imported Goods and Domestic Prices -- This presentation (video) is essentially the same thing depicted in the charts and narrative above, but if you want watch a video instead of read it, this is for you.

So What Does All This Mean?
Well, it means that when politicians (or candidates) advocate for protectionist measures, there's one central question that they must be called to answer. What is that question?
Given that protectionist measures are well understood to impose the greatest burden on lower income individuals, what measures do you intend to implement to mitigate those burdens and what is the estimated quantifiable impact of them, either as a percentage of personal income/spending or a specific sum per person?
At the very least, if a candidate or politician is going to advocate for protectionist measures, they must be held accountable to show how those measures are going to make individuals, businesses, or the society as a whole better off overall. Now the fact is that it's all but impossible to show that whatever short term gains may result from protectionist measures outweigh the long term losses, and the reason it's impossible is because there are no long term gains from protectionism.
It's About Winning Elections and Nothing More
Economists know this. I think most politicians know it too. It's the average citizen who doesn't know it. Politicians have got one primary goal: to get elected. Knowing that most voters aren't going to ask the question I noted above, politicians can focus their rhetoric on short term gains, which is what will get them elected.

Quite simply, unlike many things where it's very hard to determine how much one has lost by going "this way" instead of "that way," the losses from trade protectionism are measurable, quantifiable, and numerous times they have been measured, and it doesn't matter whether one uses standard models or alternative ones, the answer comes out the same every time: protectionism is a losing proposition overall.
At the end of the day, the thing that makes protectionist policy statements popular is politics. It's not the economics of it. It's purely and simply about getting votes. It's not about reducing costs. It's not about increasing prosperity.
Trade policies, when leveraged against your own workers, makes a nation weaker and investor class wealthier. China is taking advantage of weak U.S. leacership. But because you most likely never worked a blue collar job in your life you belive in the "magic" of free trade.

Well, I can't do anything about why and how you manage to feel as though you can legitimately assert/postulate why I accept that free trade's benefits outweigh it's downsides, most especially given the content one'll find at the links I provided in the OP.
How has so called "free trade" helped the United Stead? How does it help when Wal Mart is your top civilian employer? Would we have been a global super power in 1962 if Woolworh was are top employer? Department stores and dollar stores does not make you a strong country.

Red:
Were I were to answer that question myself or were I to point you to the documents that answer your question, would you actually read them?

I suspect the answer is "no" because:
  1. I've already shown graphically in the OP how consumer surplus is diminished by trade barriers,
  2. I've already posted several documents in the OP that answer the question,
  3. The Internet has far more documents that I have not posted here that also answer that question,
You've clearly -- as evidenced your question -- not read any of the reference documents in the OP and I doubt you'll read any of the additional ones I posted above. I think that were you to bother to read scholarly rather than editorial documents that discuss the pros and cons of free trade, you would understand how and why free trade has helped the U.S.

And I'm not going to copy and past content from those documents because when I do, folks read only that snippet and then have the nerve to refute the entire idea based on just that bit. Moreover, when folks do, they do so by merely asserting solely something to the effect of, "You don't know what you are talking about," but not at all discussing so much as a single methodological flaw and showing with equal empiricism that there is such a flaw. Perhaps they think I'm just proposing something because I just want to believe it. It has nothing to do with what I want to believe; it has only to do with what the empirical research has found.
 

Forum List

Back
Top